Clearing the Mist

Clearing the Mist is real-time commentary by Delphi Advisors on developments, clues, patterns, and events we believe could affect the U.S. economy, and particularly the Forest Products sector...

...or sometimes it's just a way to let off some steam.


Monday, September 5, 2011

Our Critique of the Debt Ceiling Decision

Note: This text was first published in the August 2011 edition of the Economic Outlook newsletter available through Forest2Market.


Perhaps the most prominent domestic economic event during July and early August involved Congressional approval of an increase in the federal debt ceiling. After a crescendo of often acrimonious debate, the debt ceiling was raised by $2.4 trillion in exchange for $2.1 trillion in budget cuts over a 10-year period. We followed the debate rather closely because we believe sovereign debt, including that of the United States, will inflict an increasing toll on economies across the globe. We were unimpressed by the debt ceiling agreement for a number of reasons, three of which are discussed below:

· First, spending will rise rather quickly (the debt increase is intended to tide the Treasury over only through the 2012 election) whereas the cuts will be spread out over the next decade (only 2 percent occur prior to the 2012 election).

Admittedly, phasing in the cuts makes some sense in light of the U.S. economy’s fragility. While we believe reducing the federal deficit and debt is necessary, we disagree with those who advocated draconian cuts as a recipe for immediately unleashing economic growth. The federal government’s contribution to GDP is variously estimated at between 9 to 16 percent, and deficit spending currently represents roughly 50 percent of that amount. Eliminating between 4.5 to 8 percent of the economy (half of the 9 to 16 percent) would initially result in a severe economic downturn. That reality seemed to have been lost in the debt-ceiling squabble.

· Second, if we could believe the small initial spending cuts were a means to navigate the difficult economic shoals, we would not be as critical. In too many past budgets, however, future cuts have been promised in return for higher near-term spending, only to never see the cuts materialize. As if to drive home that point, the debt shot up by $239 billion – eating up nearly 60 percent of the first tranche of $400 billion in new borrowing authority that was supposed to last through mid-September, and causing the debt to top 100 percent of GDP – one day after President Obama signed the bill.[1,2,3] By contrast, the proposed cuts are largely illusory; capping expenses related to fighting the wars in Iraq and Afghanistan and savings in interest on the public debt because of the lower deficits were counted as cuts.[4] Such accounting gimmickry caused one pundit to wonder why one could not assume $1 quadrillion in savings by not declaring war on Mars.[5] Moreover, the alleged cuts will only slow the rate of future spending increases.[6]

· Finally, the spending reductions were divided into two categories: $917 billion that all parties agreed to before the bill went to the president, and another $1.2 trillion to be specified later. Congress will create a Joint Select Committee (some have called it a potentially unconstitutional “Super Committee” and a “Politburo”[7]), comprised of six Democrats and six Republicans, that will be tasked with identifying the other $1.2 trillion in additional cuts. Should Congress fail to go along with the Committee’s recommendations, automatic cuts of $1.5 trillion will be triggered; those reductions would fall most heavily on the military and Medicare payments to doctors. Many are concerned the committee could raise taxes, which could put more hurdles in front of the struggling economy.[8]

To sum up, then, Congress agreed to a $2.1 trillion slowdown in the rate of spending increases during a 10-year period in which expenditures are projected to top $45.8 trillion – i.e., a 5 percent hypothetical reduction. Casey Research’s Bud Conrad produced a graph comparing the initial $917 billion in “cuts” to projected outlays. As one can see from the nearby chart, the cuts are miniscule compared to expenditures.[9]

Click image for larger view

Congressional Budget Office projections assume the United States will add another $7 trillion to the federal debt by 2021. However, if the federal government continues to borrow, as it does now, 43 cents of every dollar it intends to spend, that translates instead to an additional $20 trillion in debt. Being “mongrels” insofar as we do not subscribe completely to any particular school of economic philosophy, we nonetheless agree with the Austrian school that “debts do matter;” hence, we consider either scenario to be unsustainable. And we are not alone: “We are less than three years away from where Greece had its debt crisis,” David Walker, former U.S. comptroller general, told CNBC. Long before 2021, Walker believes we will reach a Greece-level debt-to-GDP ratio of 150 percent. “We are not exempt from a debt crisis,” Walker said. “We’re never going to default, because we can print money. [However,] we have serious interest rate risk, we have serious currency risk, we have serious inflation risk over time. If it happens, it will be sudden and it will be very painful.”[10]

Walker’s comments echoed those by the Bank of International Settlements (BIS), known as “the central bankers’ central bank,” which cautioned in a paper published in mid-July that “overall, risk premia on government debt will likely be higher and more volatile than in the past. In some countries, sovereign debt has already lost its risk-free status; in others, it may do so in the future.” The BIS warned that while the United States, Great Britain and Japan had so far been less affected by sovereign risk concerns, they were not “immune,” given their sharp increase in public debt ratios in recent years.[11]

In the case of the United States, at least, that immunity appears to be weakening. Last November, fledgling Chinese rating agency Dagong Global downgraded U.S. treasury bonds after the second round of quantitative easing commenced;[12] that downgrade was largely dismissed as a political move and ignored. In mid-July, however, rating agency Egan-Jones followed Dagong Global’s lead. Egan-Jones said its action, which cut U.S. sovereign debt to the second-highest rating, was not based on fears over the country not raising its debt ceiling. Instead, the cut was due to the U.S. debt load standing at more than 100 percent of GDP.[13] That downgrade was ignored as well, probably because Egan-Jones is not one of the “Big Three” agencies.

The markets began to pay a bit more attention, though, when Moody’s assigned a “negative” outlook to its U.S. rating in mid-July and Fitch made noises about possibly following suit. “Further measures will likely be required to ensure that the long-run fiscal trajectory remains compatible with a Aaa rating,” Moody’s said.[14] But then Standard & Poor’s delivered a “slap across the face” on 5 August by lowering its long-term U.S. debt rating from “AAA” to “AA+” along with a negative outlook[15,16] because the $2.1 trillion in budget cuts negotiated in the debt ceiling agreement were only about half the amount S&P had said in April were necessary to prevent the downgrade.[17,18,19,20] Dagong Global was quick to claim vindication, saying “S&P has proved what its Chinese counterpart has done is nothing but telling the global investors the ugly truth.”[21] At the time of this writing, the main reaction from the U.S. Treasury was to criticize S&P for not incorporating the Treasury’s more optimistic economic growth assumptions into its computations.[22]

The effects of S&P’s downgrade will probably take some time to be fully realized; in fact, given the economic turmoil in the Eurozone, yields on U.S. treasuries have fallen since the downgrade, rather than increasing as many may have expected (due to the higher degree of risk associated with the downgrade). The drop in yield since the announcement has brought much gloating in the financial press about the meaninglessness of S&P’s downgrade.[23] Most analysts acknowledge, however, that the lower yields reflect money “hiding out.” Although the U.S. economy does not look pretty, the Eurozone debt situation is even uglier, and so investors are parking money in U.S. debt until the investment situation stabilizes.

To a certain extent, the downgrade may not carry much weight if Moody’s and Fitch leave their ratings unchanged. In the grand scheme of things, wrote Michael Pento of Euro Pacific Capital, the rating agencies’ verdicts could ultimately prove largely irrelevant anyway. Yes, Pento wrote, “the fallout could be devastating to money market and pension funds that must hold AAA paper” because those institutional investors would have to dump the downgraded assets for whatever price they could get. “But an even worse outcome will occur when the real debt downgrade comes from our foreign creditors, when they no longer believe the United States has the ability to pay our bills.”[24]

Wednesday, July 6, 2011

Reducing Sovereign Debt through Financial Repression

Pruning the United States’ massive (and growing) debt down to a manageable size will not happen overnight, and a paper by Carmen Reinhart and Belen Sbrancia outlines the measures the U.S. government might employ (based upon historical precedent both in this country and elsewhere) to accomplish that task. Collectively, these measures are referred to as "financial repression" (FR). The specifics of FR have taken different forms in each of the economies where the techniques have been used, but they shared four characteristics: 1) inflation; 2) governmental control of interest rates to guarantee negative real rates of return; 3) compulsory funding of government debt by financial institutions; and 4) capital controls. We briefly discuss each point below.


1) Inflation. A deeply indebted government is likely to be tempted to reduce its debt by inflating its national currency. The rate does not have to be high so long as the government is patient, but the higher the rate of inflation, the more effective FR is at quickly reducing a nation's debt problem.

To eliminate debts incurred during WWII, the United States and Great Britain used the combination of inflation and other FR techniques to reduce their debts by an average of 3 to 4 percent of GDP per year. Given the magnitude of the debt this time around, a substantially higher rate of inflation than that experienced between 1945 and 1980 might well be necessary.

2) Negative Real Interest Rates. In theory, a government cannot inflate away its debt because the free market would demand higher interest rates to compensate for that higher rate of inflation. In practice, however, government regulations have often limited the maximum interest rates that could be paid. E.g., Regulation Q was used in the United States to prevent the payment of interest on checking accounts and to cap interest rates on savings accounts.

Regulation Q was largely phased out in the 1980s, but government control of short-term interest rates in the United States has been near absolute during the last decade. The Federal Reserve has openly used its power to keep U.S. interest rates (and hence debt service payments) as low as possible. There is no need for explicit interest rate controls so long as the Federal Reserve is able to maintain control. However, if the Fed begin to lose control (as we have been predicting it will), interest rate controls could return to the U.S. financial landscape.

As an aside, we note that investors in U.S. Treasury Bills (maturities of less than 1 year) are currently receiving negative real returns. Nominal rates ranged from 0.01 to 0.27 percent on 1-month to 1-year T-bills between 8 May and 8 June. Regardless of the inflation measure (implicit GDP deflator, CPI or PPI) all of these yields are negative in real terms. We believe this situation is due to the current uncertainty in global markets. Investors are willing to accept negative real returns rather than risk even larger losses in more volatile markets. Some of that sentiment seems to be changing, however, as China recently grabbed headlines when it was announced it had reduced its T-bill holdings by 97 percent from the peak in May 2009.

3) Involuntary Funding. In this step, the government imposes reserve or "quality" requirements on financial institutions that make holding substantial amounts of government debt mandatory -- or at least establishes overwhelming incentives for financial institutions to do so. Such requirements might be billed as mandating "financial safety" instead of the more accurate description of mandating the making of investments at below market interest rates to help overextended governments recover from financial difficulties.

4) Capital Controls. In addition to ongoing inflation that eats away the value of everyone's savings as well as the value of the government's debts, there is another necessary ingredient to FR: in Reinhart and Sbrancia's words, the "creation and maintenance of a captive domestic audience" -- i.e., mandatory participation.

In this step, the government employs techniques to prevent savers (or at least their money) from fleeing the country while systematically and deliberately destroying the purchasing power of their savings. These techniques might include explicit capital and exchange controls or other, subtler methods like tax and regulatory incentives for institutions and individuals to keep their investments "domestic."

Lest one be tempted to think financial repression is nothing but a far-out conspiracy theory, Mohamed El-Erian believes it is a distinct possibility. "It is a world where several governments in advanced economies, and the United States in particular, opt for financial repression and mild inflation as the major way to accommodate their deteriorating debt dynamics," El-Erian wrote in a report published on the firm's website. Such a situation may occur now because almost four years since the start of the financial crisis, "the world has seen little meaningful reduction in the size of the excess liabilities accumulated" beforehand, El-Erian said. "Rather than be addressed in a convincing manner, most of the excess liabilities have simply been shifted around the system, and importantly to public balance sheets and taxpayers."

Our perception of financial repression is that its tactics are likely to be employed gradually and over the long term. Of more immediate concern is how the markets will respond when the Fed ends its quantitative easing program at the end of June. Are the private sector and/or foreign governments going to be in a position to pick up where the Fed leaves off in terms of buying Treasuries (assuming Congress lifts the debt ceiling so more debt can be created)? We doubt it, in light of the realization that the Fed has been buying between 75 and 85 percent of the Treasuries offered since the end of 2010. The implications of such a scenario are that, with the largest buyer of Treasury debt sitting on the sidelines and no other parties able (or at least willing) to plug the gap left by the Fed's departure, interest rates might finally turn higher as bond prices fall from lack of demand.

Monday, June 20, 2011

Of GDP Growth and Deflators: Smoke and Mirrors?

The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) kept its estimate of the annualized growth rate of 1Q2011 gross domestic product (GDP) essentially unchanged at 1.8 percent, but shifted some components’ contributions around. For example, personal consumption expenditures (PCE) were nearly 0.4 percent weaker than previously reported while private domestic investment (PDI) was stronger by about the same amount -- thanks to increases in fixed investments and inventory building. Although both exports and imports grew relative to the prior (advance) report, the changes left the contribution of net exports (NetX) to the overall growth rate virtually the same as the original estimate. Government consumption expenditures (GCE) also changed very little.

Click image for larger version

Largely ignored among all the ink spilled discussing the importance of declining government expenditures, changes in trade, and consumer spending in causing the drop from 4Q2010’s 3.1 percent growth rate was a huge shift in the GDP deflator used to remove the effects of price inflation from nominal GDP: from a 0.4 percent annualized change in 4Q2010 to 1.9 percent in 1Q2011. That represents a quarter-to-quarter increase of 375 percent in the broadest measure of price inflation across the U.S. economy. The following is admittedly simplistic, but had the 1Q2011 change in the GDP deflator remained at 0.4 percent, the advance GDP would have come in closer to 3.3 percent than the reported 1.8 percent.

We are not complaining, though, because the growth rate also could have been much worse. The Consumer Metrics Institute (CMI) has been observing that changes in the GDP deflator have been unusually small relative to corresponding changes in both the consumer (CPI) and producer (PPI) price indices for the past couple of quarters. Because the GDP deflator corrects for price changes at both the consumer and producer levels, one might expect the change in its value during any given quarter to lie between the concurrent changes in the CPI and PPI. As we show below, that has been true on average but changes in the GDP deflator have often exceeded those boundaries during individual quarters.

To test whether CMI’s contention is true, we computed annualized quarter-to-quarter percentage changes in the GDP deflator, the CPI for urban consumers, and the PPI between 1Q1950 and the present. We then subtracted the quarterly CPI and PPI percentage changes from the corresponding changes in the GDP deflator; the differences were negative when the GDP deflator’s percentage changes were smaller than those of the CPI and/or PPI, and positive when the GDP deflator’s percentage changes were larger than those of the CPI and/or PPI (the nearby table contains an example of these calculations).

Click image for larger version

As mentioned above, the average differences between the changes in the GDP deflator and changes in the CPI and/or PPI have been quite small over time (evidenced by the proximity of the symbols to zero during the 1Q1950-to-4Q2009 period in the figure below). However, wide disparities have often occurred during individual quarters (shown by the length of the range bars radiating from the symbols in the figure below). In some recent quarters (e.g., 2Q and 3Q2010) the GDP deflator’s percentage change has essentially equaled that of either the CPI or PPI, but in other cases the differences have been marked. 1Q2011 is a good example of the latter: In less than 4 percent of the quarters since 1Q1950 have the differences between the percentage change in the GDP deflator and the percentage change in the CPI been more negative than in 1Q2011; only once (in 1Q1974) was the difference between the percentage change in the GDP deflator and the percentage change in the PPI more negative. Hence, we conclude CMI’s contention is valid.

Click image for larger version

Who cares, you say? Then consider this: Had the 1Q2011 change in the GDP deflator more closely resembled that of the CPI, the BEA’s estimate of growth likely would have been just barely positive; if more like the PPI, the economy would have been shown as contracting.

This issue is equally important during upcoming quarters. What is the probability that changes in the GDP deflator will continue to be so small relative to those of either the CPI or PPI? We think that probability is quite small. So, if changes in the GDP deflator come back into closer alignment with changes in the CPI or PPI and price inflation picks up speed as we expect, reported real growth will disappear under that statistical “double whammy.”